Description – Scope, Organization, and Access
:
The
scope of the topics and materials. Each kind of
social inequality – such as class or gender – has distinctive dynamics and
each concrete instance of inequality has historically and culturally
specific characteristics. Yet, all social inequalities also share
critical common effects and requirements for persistence. For
example, all social inequalities produce legitimating ideologies, all
must curb resistance, all have to transfer the unequal resources and
positions to new generations, all produce divergent interests. To
understand a structural characteristic of some kind of inequality – such
as legitimation processes in a class system or violence in gender
inequality – we want to recognize that they represent a combination of the
dynamics common to most inequality systems and the specific
characteristics of that type of inequality. The topics below
pursue a series of fundamental questions about social inequalities,
seeking to investigate the general dynamics of inequalities, comparing
these dynamics across different types of inequality. Examples of
these topics include: what are the roles of interests in various kinds
of inequalities, how is inequality sustained across generations, what
processes induce conformity among both the advantaged and disadvantaged,
what mechanisms prevent rebellion, and what decides the intensity of
inequalities?
The readings represent the core of the stratification field in
sociology, the materials that sociologists working in this area expect
other others in the area to know, plus materials needed to pursue
important analytic issues under represented in the field.
The class
organization and goals. The class is intended for both
beginning and advanced graduate students. Critical
requirements for taking this course are a strong interest in inequality
and a commitment to the class project of investigating new ideas.
In this class, each week's activities will be organized around an
analytical task, as well as a set of readings. Rather than
focusing on discussion of the readings, the analytical tasks involve
attempting an analysis of inequality related to the week's issue,
building on the materials we read (in brief papers of 2-3 pages).
While mastering the existing research and theory is obviously a
prerequisite to doing good work, the approach in this class seeks to
develop analytical skills as well as understandings of the literature by
stressing actual analyses of inequality rather discussions of the
literature.
The course readings stress the foundational sociological literature on
inequality. Each week we will all look at some common
readings. The course guide will also point toward a range of other
recommended and related readings for further study for each topic -
students are not expected to read these optional materials as part of
the course. The recommended and related readings represent what a
student seeking to specialize in this area might read. Students in the
class are encouraged to scan these optional lists each week and look at
any pieces that seem particularly valuable or interesting.
All class meetings are organized as discussions. Part of our
class discussions will be on the common readings and part on students'
efforts to explore the analytical tasks each week. We will
adjust the time devoted to these two goals according to our experiences
over the class. Every week, students will initiate discussions on
readings and papers. To see the discussant responsibilities for
each week, go to:
analysis.of.inequality/Discussants.html
The readings below (the recommended and related readings as well as
the common readings that are the basis of the course) are almost all
available online – simply click the links to get to the articles.
For convenience, some readings are selections (excerpts from articles or
books) that appear in two printed collections that are now available
online: articles with "[Grusky – Classic]" appended to the listing are
from Inequality: Classic Readings in Race, Class, & Gender,
2006, eds. David B. Grusky and Szonja Szelènyi; articles with "[Grusky -
Contemporary]" appended are from Inequality Reader: Contemporary
& Foundational Readings in Race, Class, & Gender, 2006,
eds. David B. Grusky and Szonja Szelènyi – for most of the selections
from these readers, alternative citations and links are also provided
for the original publication or an appropriate alternative.Note:
Links for all readings will appear in the online version of the course
guide.
A note on the "hidden" material
below: Each section of this guide includes –
beside the common readings – three subsections, one for an analytical
task, one for recommended readings, and one for related
readings. To simplify navigating through the course guide,
only the headings for these subsections are initially visible. The
content of all these subsections are hidden (so that the beginning
appearance of the page is similar to a standard syllabus) until the
viewer clicks on the subsection heading, then its contents will
appear. While this organization is helpful for negotiating the
page most of the time, it can become an obstacle if we want to search
the page (for example, for a particular article) as searches will ignore
the hidden material. To overcome this limitation, it is possible
to show all the hidden sections by clicking the § symbol at the top
of the page (and simply reload the page to
collapse all the "hidden" sections to their usual look). The table
of contents at the top of the page will still work to aid speedy
navigation to any section.
The Topics
I. Introduction
The first class meeting will involve introductory discussions of the
class objectives.
- Analytical
Task
- No task for introductory meeting
- Common Readings
- No readings for introductory meeting. Students with limited
relevant background might usefully peruse any standard textbook on
stratification before the first class meeting.
- Recommended
Readings
- Peter M. Blau. "A
Fable about Social Structure." Social
Forces, Vol. 58, No. 3 (Mar., 1980), pp. 777-788.
On the importance of always considering the implications of
numbers. [jstor: 2577184]
- ...
- Related
Readings
II. What do we mean by social inequality?
How can we conceive of and talk about social inequality in ways that are
general enough to apply across the range of relevant phenomena, consistent
enough to minimize conceptual ambiguities, and precise enough to be
analytically effective? Inequality is ubiquitous. People are
unequal in every conceivable way in endless circumstances, both immediate
and enduring, by both objective criteria and subjective experience.
So, what counts as social inequality? Can we characterize it
in ways that let us confidently and impartially assess when there is more
or less of it?
- Analytical
Task
- Analytical task: What is social inequality?
We often think that the meaning of social inequality is
self-evident or easy. Perhaps it is when we focus on extreme
versions of the more obvious forms of social inequality, such as
the rich compared to the poor. But, equally, perhaps it is
not when we consider inequalities that are subler or more
complex, such as those based on sexual preference or ethnic
identity or between nations. We want to begin by looking a
little deeper into our conceptualization of social inequalities.
- Choose two kinds of inequality. For each kind of
inequality, consider an example showing a high degree of
inequality and another showing equality or a minimal amount of
inequality. Here we are simply trying to conceive a simple 2
x 2 table, showing two kinds of inequality and two levels of
inequality for each kind. This is the simplest design for
doing social analyses, whether that analysis is empirical or
theoretical. (Note: It is fine to use standard, commonly
discussed kinds of inequality, but being original and creative
about kinds of inequality to consider is also good.)
- Describe (briefly) how the relevant groups are unequal for
each type. For each of these two kinds of inequality,
try to list the main ways that those affected are
unequal. For now, do not worry about why
such inequality exists. For now we are concerned with what
we mean by inequality, not what causes it. Try to specify
the crucial experiences, opportunities, or other circumstances
that distinguish the beneficiaries of the inequality from those
who are disadvantaged. Consider also the relationships
between the disadvantaged and advantaged, both direct and
indirect. (The idea of "indirect relationships"
refers to ways that the advantaged or disadvantaged influence the
circumstances or actions of those who are differently situated
without direct interaction, e.g. by controlling government
policies or creating a culture of fear.) In short, for each
of the two types of inequality, what induces us to call one
example high inequality and another low?
- A final question. After working through the
questions above, try to complete a definition sentence beginning "In
general, social inequality exists when ... ." The goal
of this sentence is to provide a definition of social inequality
general enough to embrace the range of social inequalities but
also precise enough to distinguish social inequality from its
absence. The implicit strategy is compare what social
inequality means for the two chosen examples, then to try to
identify the common conditions that make them (and other forms)
all merit being called "social inequality" (distinguished from the
characteristics specific to certain types of inequality or
concrete historical and cultural conditions). To do this
involves not only the empirical comparison, but the appropriate
conceptual abstraction.
- For the ambitious (to develop a
deeper grasp)...
- Here are some other issues that you
might integrate into your initial assessment of inequalities
- Vantage points. Might
some people (scholars, political actors, others) disagree
that any of the components you identify should really be
considered inequality? If so, why?
(The goal here is to think through the reasons that people
disagree about what should be called inequality?)
- Try to figure out how we might measure
the amount of inequality. Of the ways that you
have listed people being unequal, select which of these
differences seem most important. What might be
reasonable ways to measure each identified facet
of inequality? For each kind of inequality you have
selected an example where inequality is high and another
where it is low. Can you think of a measurement
procedure that will allow one to look at any society or
group and determine if some aspect of inequality is high,
medium, or low? Focus on realistic means that could be
applied in research, that could be used for the same aspects
of inequality when they apply to other kinds of
inequality. Do this only for the two or three facets
of inequality in your examples that seem most decisive.
- For each of the two types of
inequality, if we put aside differences in the circumstances
of advantaged and disadvantaged people, what important
differences in social organization distinguish societies (or
other social groupings such as communities or organizations)
where that type of inequality is high from those where it is
low? The goal here is to consider if societies (or
other levels of social organization containing inequality)
that have high levels of some type of inequality
consistently differ from societies that have low levels, in
ways other than the difference in the level of this kind of
inequality.
- Most people responding to the
prompts above will think about inequality between kinds of
people. Consider two other important concerns.
First, inequality may be between positions rather than
people (this is a critical concern which we will address
later). Second, inequality may concern "units" other
that people, such as families or organizations or nations.
- Common Readings
- David B. Grusky and Manwai C. Ku. "Gloom,
Doom, and Inequality." Pp. 2-28 in Social
Stratification: Class, Race, and Gender in Sociological
Perspective, 3rd edition, edited by David B. Grusky, Manwai C.
Ku and Szonja Szelényi. Boulder: Westview Press. [available online
from Grusky]
- Randall Collins. "Lenski's
Power Theory of Economic Inequality: A Central Neglected Question
in Stratification Research." Sociological Theory,
(2004) 22: 219-228. [doi: 10.1111/j.0735-2751.2004.00213.x]
- William Julius Wilson.
"The Declining Significance of Race." Society. 15:2
(1978): 56-62. [doi: 10.1007/BF03181003]; also Wilson,
Response to Reviews of Declining Significance ...
. Contemporary Sociology. 9:1 (1980): 21-24. [jstor:
2065555]
- Paula England. "The
Gender Revolution: Uneven and Stalled." Gender &
Society 24:2 (Apr 2010): 149-166. (see also England's
response to critics, "Reassessing ...", under Recommended Readings)
[doi: 10.1177/0891243210361475]
- Recommended
Readings
- Related
Readings
- Archibald O. Haller. "Societal
Stratification." Encyclopedia of Sociology. 2nd ed.
Vol. 4. New York: Macmillan Reference USA, 2001. 2864-2874. Gale
Virtual Reference Library.
- Pennock, J. Roland. "Equality
and Inequality." In The Oxford Companion to the Politics
of the World, (2001) Oxford University Press.
- ...
III. What are common forms of social inequality?
What is the range of social inequalities that we should be addressing?
Pundits, scholars, and ordinary people usually focus on the couple
forms of inequality they experience as most troubling. Contemporary
sociology's sometimes blinkered perspective is reflected in the many
readers and texts on race, class, and gender. The range of analytically
relevant inequalities is considerably wider.
- Analytical
Task
- Analytical Task: This week's task is to identify
major forms of inequality in two societies. The goal
is to see the range of inequalities that exist in
different societies. The remainder of this task description
just tries to show how to approach this systematically.
- To start, choose two societies with which you have some
familiarity. It is fine to use this society or an another
society in which you have lived as one example (but it is an
interesting challenge to use two societies you have not
experienced). The two societies can be from two different
parts of the world or from different points in time. The
main goal is to use two societies that differ significantly in
their structure and culture, regardless whether those differences
reflect location, culture, historical circumstance, or something
else.
- For each example (society), identify the significant,
widely-present forms of social inequality that persist
over time.
- "widely present" means not limited to certain locations nor
small parts of the population; note that many instances of
inequality that are limited to particular places or subgroups
are, however, examples of some more generally defined kind of
inequality, so moving to a higher level of generality or
categorization identifies a widely present inequality of which
they are specific examples
- two or more instances of inequality with a similar system or
structure but involving different populations should usually
be considered to of the same kind (e.g., similar ethnic
inequality processes or structures may apply to Hindi and
Chinese minorities)
- The aim here is not to see how long the list of inequalities
might be, but we do want to see how diverse the forms of
inequality can be, and to consider if important kinds of
inequality are overlooked.
- Try to describe briefly each form of inequality
identified (for each society), by indicating:
- to what degree is the inequality more a continuous gradation
(like years of age) or more a division into distinct
categories (like employed vs. unemployed)
- what is unequal, that is what are the assets, opportunities,
capacities, relationships, or whatever that define the
inequality by their unequal distribution (this is not
what explains the inequality, but simply what is
unequal); this is self-evident for some kinds of inequality,
but not for others.
- who is advantaged and who disadvantaged; in
essence, this asks how are the advantaged people different
from the disadvantaged people not only in the advantages that
define the inequality, but in other ways as well (e.g. for
ethnic inequalities, the groups are, in theory, defined by
ethnic identity [although ethnicity is tricky]; distinguishing
characteristics for some kinds of inequality might be more
difficult to characterize, and could, in theory, not exist if
placement is random)
- [optional – how do the disadvantaged and the
advantaged perceive the inequality?; do they have similar or
different conceptions of what is unequal, why they are
disadvantaged or advantaged, whether it is fair, and the
like?]
- In short, for two societies, you are preparing a list
of outstanding inequalities, that gives the primary
characteristics of each kind of inequality. You could make
this either as two lists or as two simple tables.
- Finally, having prepared a catalog of the primary forms
of social inequality in the two societies, how would you compare
the two societies with respect to their patterns of social
inequality? All we are looking for here are initial,
outstanding differences and similarities (note that similarities
are at least as important as differences). To be clear, we
are just looking for an initial impression – a comprehensive
comparison would be a major project, obviously far beyond our
scope.
- If this aspect of the analysis seems baffling, overwhelming,
or obscure initially, consider the following questions.
Does the overall amount of inequality seem greater in one
society than the other or similar or does this seem impossible
to guess? Do the structures of the societies or their
potential for change seem to be dominated by different or
similar inequalities? Does inequality overall seem more
rigid in one society than the other? Do major forms of
inequality seem to overlap a lot, or are they distinctive and
rather independent from each other? Is inequality more
continuous in one society and more categorical in the
other?
- For the ambitious with time to go
further:
- How might we categorize the varied
forms of inequality discerned in the two societies into
groups defined by some notable similarities? For
example, if we have twelve types of inequality initially,
could we usefully fit them into two or three categories that
reflect their similarities (and differences)? Here are
some examples of criteria that might be used to categorize
inequalities:
- Consider the processes
producing them
- Consider who is advantaged and
disadvantaged
- Consider how one form affects
the others
- Consider their legitimacy claims
- Consider their histories
- Consider any other reasonable
logic you can conceive for grouping them, remembering
that a useful analytic taxonomy will usually rely on
some aspect of causation
- Do any of the forms of social
inequality seem more important to the structure and
organizational dynamics of a society than do others?
If so, why?
- Common Readings
- Recommended
Readings
- Anthony Giddens. "Elites
in the British Class Structure." The
Sociological Review, 20 (1972): 345?372.
- Alejandro Portes and Robert D. Manning. "The
Immigrant Enclave: Theory and Empirical Examples."
- But compare: Roger Waldinger. "The
Ethnic Enclave Debate Revisited." International
Journal of Urban and Regional Research, (1993), 17:
444?452. [doi: 10.1111/j.1468-2427.1993.tb00232.x]
- John H. Goldthorpe and Keith Hope. "Occupational
Grading and Occupational Prestige." Social
Science Information October 1972 11: 17-73.
(especially pp. 19-33) [doi: 10.1177/053901847201100502]
- John Mullahy, Stephanie Robert, and Barbara Wolfe. "Health,
Income, and Inequality." Russell Sage Foundation Working
Paper Series. 2003.
- William Julius Wilson. "Jobless
Poverty: A New Form of Social Dislocation, in the Inner-City
Ghetto." (1999) [Grusky Contemporary]
{Alternative: William Julius Wilson. "
When
Work Disappears." Political Science Quarterly , Vol. 111,
No. 4 (Winter, 1996-1997), pp. 567-595. [jstor: 2152085]}
-
-
- Related
Readings
IV. What distinguishes legitimate from illegitimate
forms of inequality?
We often use the term inequality to refer only to forms of
inequality we consider unjust or otherwise undesirable. Yet, much
inequality is commonly accepted as appropriate, fair, or desirable in
societies. The amount of legitimacy attributed to a form of
inequality can be anywhere between extremely high (e.g. the authority of
parents over infants) to extremely low (e.g., slavery in a modern society
with well-developed civil rights). The assessment of
legitimacy should always consider potential differences among
differentially situated groups (e.g., those enjoying advantages in a
system of inequality, those disadvantaged, and those relatively
unaffected), and the degree of agreement or disagreement about legitimacy
assessments. Analytically, we want to ask what processes or
conditions cause a form of inequality to be considered more or less
legitimate. When does the legitimacy status of inequality change or
become contested?
- Analytical
Task
- Analytical task: Using examples of two kinds of
inequality, consider what circumstances appear to foster or to
erode the acceptance of the inequality as legitimate.
- First, select two kinds of inequality.
These can be from any place or time, but it might be simpler if
they coexist in the same society. They do not need to be
inequalities considered socially "important." For each
kind of inequality, select one example or circumstance with
high "legitimacy" when those involved appear accepting or
complacent and another example or circumstance with
low "legitimacy" when those involved contest the
inequality. Thus you are considering four examples in all,
two that are uncontested, high legitimacy and two that are
contested, low legitimacy, based on the two types of
inequality. This is, once again, the simplest comparative
design for social analysis, essentially a two by two table, with
one direction being the two kinds of inequality and the other
being the two levels of legitimacy. (Whether an inequality
is perceived as legitimate and whether it is contested are not the
same, but we are simplifying for our current goals.)
- Second, for each of the two kinds of inequality,
describe what are the principal arguments or claims offered
by the advantaged (or their representatives) to defend or
explain the system of inequality in the examples you have
chosen.
- Look for arguments that respond to three common claims in
defense of inequality, that it is (1) just, (2)
necessary, and (3) beneficial to all.
- Where possible, identify the general cultural beliefs or
symbols from which the arguments seek to gain acceptance or
weight, such as religious beliefs, science, or fear of
outsiders.
- Is it possible to distinguish between claims that seem to be
historically or culturally contingent and those more
fundamental to the particular kind of inequality?
[Explanatory note: If we compare organized religions we find
that all have practices and rituals for marriage. Many
of the specific rituals are artifacts of the historical
conditions in which they emerged, and would just as
effectively if they were different. Some aspects of
these practices, such as significant property exchanges (e.g.,
bride price) may reflect functional needs of the prevailing
economic and kinship system, although their concrete
manifestation can vary. Some even more general aspects,
such as requirement of marriage to identify kinship
relationships of children may reflect fundamental requirements
for the functional order of any kinship system. Claims
about inequality can similarly be categorized from the
historically arbitrary to those that seem unavoidable.]
- Third, when describing the legitimacy claims, consider
if the claims when the inequality is contested differ from
when its acceptance is largely unproblematic. That is, for each of
the two kinds of inequality, what seems to distinguish the
examples where legitimacy claims succeed from those where they
fail?
- When the disadvantaged seem to accept legitimacy claims,
which arguments appear to be convincing or acceptable to
them? Why do they accept these?
- When the disadvantaged question and contest the legitimacy
of the inequality, what are the principal counter arguments
they use? Their counter arguments suggest how the
legitimacy claims are failing.
- In short, you are developing a description of the ways
that people try to legitimate two kinds of inequalities, comparing
examples where the legitimacy efforts succeed with examples where
they do not. The goal is not to explain the range of these
claims or when they succeed, but to get a first level sense of
what legitimacy claims are and why they are important.
- Finally, in response to the preceding analysis you have
developed of legitimacy claims regarding four examples of
inequality (based on two types of inequality), try to state
three general hypotheses about legitimacy claims, the role
of legitimacy, or conflicts over legitimacy in systems of
inequality. Elaborate each of these hypotheses just enough
that we can understand what they mean and what motivates
them.
- These are hypotheses, which means they are not
theories and not claims we can defend. Rather, we can
think of them as informed speculations about what might be
true. They are ideas worth researching or worth thinking
about if trying to develop a theory about the legitimation of
inequality. Essentially, this is asking what ideas
spring to mind as a result of doing the empirical comparisons
in this task.
- Common Readings
- Thomas Luckmann. "Comments
on Legitimation." Current Sociology June 1987 35:
109-117. [doi:10.1177/001139287035002011] (the entire issue
containing this article was on legitimation – click the link on the
article page to the "Table of Contents" to see what this
includes) [doi: 10.1177/001139287035002011]
- Talcott Parsons. "Max
Weber and the Contemporary Political Crisis: I. The Sociological
Analysis of Power and Authority Structures." The Review of
Politics, Vol. 4, No. 1 (Jan., 1942), pp. 61-76.
- Martin E. Spencer. "Weber
on Legitimate Norms and Authority." The British Journal of
Sociology, Vol. 21, No. 2 (Jun., 1970), pp. 123-134
- Robert N. Bellah. "Legitimation
Processes in Politics and Religion." Current Sociology
June 1987 35: 89-99. [doi: 10.1177/001139287035002009]
- Robert Max Jackson, Destined for Equality, pp. 146-157
on "Meritocratic Norms". (Also see excerpts from Jackson
in Interests section below.)
- Recommended
Readings
- Background: Ch. 2 "Power,
Authority and the State." In Shaun Best, Introduction
to Politics and Society. Sage, 2002. (A textbook
introduction to legitimacy and authority work.) [doi:
10.4135/9781446220832]
- Walter A. Weisskopf. "The
Dialectics of Equality." Annals of the American
Academy of Political and Social Science, Vol. 409, Income
Inequality (Sep., 1973), pp. 163-173 [doi:
10.1177/000271627340900118; jstor: 1041502]
- Joan Acker; "Inequality
Regimes: Gender, Class, and Race in Organizations"; Gender
& Society, vol. 20, no. 4, pp. 441-464, Aug 2006 [doi:
10.1177/0891243206289499]
- Lars Osberg and Timothy Smeeding. "'Fair'
Inequality? Attitudes toward Pay Differentials: The United
States in Comparative Perspective." American
Sociological Review Vol. 71, No. 3 (Jun., 2006), pp.
450-473 [doi: 10.1177/000312240607100305]
- Mérove Gijsberts. "The
Legitimation of Income Inequality in State-Socialist and Market
Societies." Acta Sociologica, Vol. 45, No. 4 (2002),
pp. 269-285 [doi: 10.1177/000169930204500402] [jstor: 4194946]
- David Miller. "Distributive
Justice: What the People Think." Ethics, Vol. 102,
No. 3 (Apr., 1992), pp. 555-593. [jstor: 2381840]
- James Konow. "Is
fairness in the eye of the beholder? An impartial spectator
analysis of justice." Social Choice and Welfare, 33 (1):
101-127 Jun 2009 [doi: 10.1007/s00355-008-0348-2]
- Steven Brint, Jerome Karabel. "American
Education, Meritocratic Ideology, and the Legitimation of
Inequality: The Community College and the Problem of American
Exceptionalism." Higher Education, Vol. 18, No. 6
(1989), pp. 725-735 [doi: 10.1007/BF00155663; jstor:
3447109]
- Rosamund E. Stock. "Explaining
the Choice of Distribution Rule: The Role of Mental
Representations." Sociological Inquiry Volume
73, Issue 2: 177189, May 2003 [doi: 10.1111/1475-682X.00051]
- Related
Readings
- Jürgen Habermas. Legitimation Crisis. Beacon
Press. 1975.
- James Konow. "Which
Is the Fairest One of All? A Positive Analysis of Justice
Theories." Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLI
(December 2003) pp. 11881239 [doi:
10.1257/002205103771800013]
- Sutphin, Suzanne Taylor; Simpson, Brent. "The
role of self-evaluations in legitimizing social inequality."
Social Science Research, vol. 38, no. 3, pp. 609-621, Sep
2009 [doi: 10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.01.007]
- Langer, Ellen J.; Blank, Arthur; Chanowitz, Benzion. "The
mindlessness of ostensibly thoughtful action: The role of
"placebic" information in interpersonal interaction."
Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, Vol 36(6),
Jun 1978, 635-642 [doi: 10.1037/0022-3514.36.6.635]
- Robert Max Jackson. Down So Long (unpublished
ms.). Disputed
Ideals: Ideologies of Domesticity and Feminist Rebellion
V. What is the critical distinction between positional
inequality and status inequality?
To put it simply, positional inequality refers to inequalities
between "positions" such as the different levels in an organizational
hierarchy (e.g., president, divisional manager, supervisor, clerk).
These locations give their advantages and disadvantages to the people who
circulate through them. Status inequality refers to social
advantages and disadvantages that adhere to categories of people without
regard to the positions they hold (such as race). Grasping the
differences between these two "types" of inequality and the relationships
between them is crucial for analytic clarity. (This distinction has
some similarity to the common contrast between achieved status and
ascribed status, but it is analytically different. Our distinction
stresses the way inequality is socially organized while the
achieved/ascribed concepts refer to the ways people acquire a
characteristic.)
- Analytical
Task
- Analytical task: How do positional and status
inequalities differ and how are those differences important?
- Select two examples of positional inequalities and two
examples of status inequalities. The examples may be two
fundamentally different kinds of positional (or status) inequality
or they may be two distinctive instances of the same kind of
inequality appearing in different societies (e.g., racial
inequality in a plantation economy and racial inequality in a
market economy). It will probably be easier to use four
reasonably concrete examples (such as contemporary racial
inequality in Britain). Using more general categories (such
as racial inequality in market economies) is a more ambitious
strategy.
- As usual, for each type of inequality, clearly describe who
are the advantaged and the disadvantaged and how they are
unequal.
- Enumerate the characteristics that distinguish the two
examples of positional inequality from the two examples of
status inequality. To put it differently, in what ways are
both examples of positional inequality different from both
examples of status inequality? Examples of things to
consider include (but should not be limited to):
- homogeneity of people sharing similar standing (i.e., level
of [dis]advantage)
- intergenerational rigidity (likelihood of having same
standing as parents)
- ways that people's standing may improve or decline over time
- diffuseness of impact on people's lives (i.e., what
proportion of people's time, activities, and relationships are
highly influenced)
- legal status and government role in regulating, preserving,
or challenging the inequality
- legitimation processes (content of the justifying ideology,
who or what promotes the legitimacy)
- historical roots of the inequality structure
- For each difference you identify above between the positional
and status inequalities, please
- briefly describe how the positional and status inequalities
seem to differ with respect to this characteristic, and,
- if you can, suggest what might explain the difference (or,
to put it differently, suggest why you would expect this
difference to distinguish other examples of status and
positional inequalities).
- In short: We are making an initial effort to
identify general ways that systems of positional inequality differ
from systems of status inequality. The goal is to produce a
list of plausible differences, and to get a first sense of what
form these differences will take and why they appear.
- note that we are again using a very basic "research design,"
comparing two examples of positional inequality with two
examples of status inequality; this is the simplest possible
design for trying to identify differences between two
categories (as we must have at least two examples of each
category to make the simplest control for other sources of
variation among the phenomena being categorized, in this case
instances of social inequality)
- Finally: Based on the differences you enumerate and
explore from your examples, what hypotheses do you have about
general differences between positional and status inequalities?
- Common Readings
- excerpts
on positional vs status inequality from Robert Max Jackson, Destined
for Equality
- Max Weber:
- Class,
Status, Party [this is a new translation, "The
distribution of power within the community: Classes, Stände,
Parties," Journal of Classical Sociology (2010) 10: 137]
[doi: 10.1177/1468795X10361546]
- Social
Stratification and Class Structure [from Max Weber:
The Theory of Social and Economic Organization. Translated
by A. M. Henderson and Talcott Parsons. (Free Press, Glencoe,
IL, 1947). pp. 424-429]; (Also appears as "Status Groups and
Classes," Part 1, Ch IV, pp. 302-7 in Economy
and Society.)
-
Open and Closed Relationships (section 10 only, located in
pp. 139-143, part of "Fundamental Concepts of Sociology" [also
from Max Weber: The Theory of Social and Economic
Organization. ]) (Also appears as "Open and Closed
Relationships" Part1, Ch 1, Sect 10, pp. 43-6 in Economy
and Society.)
- Karl Marx –
Classes in Capitalism and Pre-Capitalism
[Grusky – Classic]
- Charles Tilly, "Rethinking
Inequality", Polish Sociological Review
3(151) (2005): 207-219
- Recommended
Readings
- excerpt on
discrimination from Robert Max Jackson, Destined for
Equality
-
Symposium on Inequality, Contemporary Sociology 29
(2000):775-818. [jstor: i325498]
- Barbara F. Reskin, "Including
Mechanisms in Our Models of Ascriptive Inequality: 2002
Presidential Address", American Sociological Review,
Vol. 68, No. 1 (Feb., 2003), pp. 1-21 [jstor: 3088900]
- Max Weber,
sections on Social Aspects Of The Division Of Labour (18)
through Types of Communal Organization of Labour (26), pp.
228-266 of Max Weber: The Theory of Social and Economic
Organization. Translated by A. M. Henderson and Talcott
Parsons. (Free Press, Glencoe, IL, 1947)
- Related
Readings
VI. How do we understand "honor" status hierarchies,
that lack apparent material bases?
Academia is one good example of a well-developed system (or systems) of
honorific inequality. High school peer groups are often good
examples of short-lived patterns of reputational inequality. The
idea of celebrity is usually associated with unequal prestige. The
key to honorific inequalities is that people compete for recognition and
deference, rather than material goods, power, or opportunities.
Purely honorific inequality structures are rare, as the pursuit of
prestige is commonly intermingled with materialistic inequities. The study
of honor and prestige systems (other than in the specialized form of
occupational prestige) is underdeveloped in sociology. Theoretical
works recognize its significance, but most treat honorific inequality as
both causally derivative and of marginal importance when compared to
economic and political inequalities. While prestige and honor are
elusively intangible, we are likely to misunderstand any type of
inequality if they are ignored.
- Analytical
Task
- Analytical task: What do non-material
inequalities of honor or prestige look like in practice and what
is the logic of their processes?
- Select two (or more) examples of honorific inequality
systems, where people "compete" directly for recognition,
respect, and deference. Such systems often include income and
power rewards. But we are looking for forms of inequality
where honorific status is central. Here are several
reasonable identifying characteristics to consider:
- Does honor (or prestige or the like) motivate competition
for desirable locations as much as does power or material
rewards?
- Is deference to others determined as much by their perceived
prestige as by their structural position, wealth, authority,
or the like?
- In general, are honor or prestige acts at least as much a
cause of material rewards as it is a result of them?
- For each inequality system selected, try to
develop an analytical assessment of the way it works by responding
to these:
- Identify and describe as well as you can what
conveys or is experienced as honor; consider how it
looks both from within and from outside; think about ways that
the lives of those with more honor differ from the lives of
those with less; also, think about how we know which people
have more honor, or to put it differently, how we know to whom
we should defer and who should defer to us. (Think about
titles, awards, forms of dress, access to activities, and so
forth.)
- Describe what people do to gain honor or to compete
for honor.
- What decides the distribution of honor overall
within each system? Consider what processes and which
people decide who has more honor. Is it controlled from
the top or the bottom? Are people aware who decides the
outcomes?
- What induces people to accept and conform
to the expectations of the prestige system? Why do they
defer to those who possess more honor? (Consider both
the carrots and the sticks.)
- Compare these systems of honor and prestige to
the systems of positional and status inequality we have
considered. Try to identify two or more important
differences and two or more important similarities,
explaining as best you can why you think each of these differences
and similarities exist.
- In short, the aim of this week's task is to compare two
specific examples of honor inequality systems (and secondarily
compare them to inequalities where honor is secondary) to get an
initial sense of how honor inequality systems work.
- Common Readings
- Recommended
Readings
- Elliot B. Weininger. "Foundations
of Pierre Bourdieu's class analysis." Pp. 82-118 in Erik
Olin Wright (ed). Approaches to Class Analysis. Cambridge
University Press, 2005. Cambridge Books Online.
[10.1017/CBO9780511488900.005] [doi:
10.1017/CBO9780511488900"]
- Bernd Wegener, "Concepts
and Measurement of Prestige," Annual Review of Sociology,
Vol. 18, (1992), pp. 253-280 [doi:
10.1146/annurev.so.18.080192.001345]
- Donald J. Treiman "A
Standard Occupational Prestige Scale for Use with Historical
Data." The Journal of Interdisciplinary History,
Vol. 7, No. 2, (Autumn, 1976), pp. 283-304 [jstor: 202737]
- John H. Goldthorpe and Keith Hope. "Occupational
Grading and Occupational Prestige." Social Science
Information 1972 11: 17-73 (see pp. 19-23, 26-33) [doi:
10.1177/053901847201100502]
- Related
Readings
- Francis Flynn, "How
much should I give and how often? The effects of generosity and
frequency of favor exchange on social status and productivity,"
Academy of Management Journal Oct 2003, Vol. 46 Issue 5,
pp.539-553 [jstor: 30040648]
- Thorstein Veblen –
The Theory of the Leisure Class (1899) [Grusky -
Classic] [also compare potlatch]
- Rebecca L. Sandefur, "Work
and Honor in the Law: Prestige and the Division of Lawyers'
Labor," American Sociological Review, Vol. 66, No. 3
(Jun., 2001), pp. 382-403 [jstor: 3088885]
VII. How do people experience inequality and why do
these experiences matter?
Research on inequalities commonly treats experience as a simple effect
of inequality; interesting but secondary to theory and explanation.
Here we want to think of experience not only as a result, but also as a
potential ingredient to the explanation of inequalities. The
experiences of inequalities can serve as strong motivating forces at all
levels. The experiences also encompass not only the outcomes of
inequality, but all the processes that sustain or challenge it.
- Analytical
Task
- Analytical task: How do lower-status and
higher-status people experience inequalities and their locations
within them? With what consequences for the systems of
inequality?
- Select two systems of inequality: one in which
you have (now or in the past) been in a relatively low-status
location and another system in which you have been in a relatively
high-status location. The point here is to select systems in
which you have observational knowledge about the experience of
inequality. If possible, use a form of positional inequality
for one example and status inequality for the other, but it okay
if that is too much of a stretch given your biography.
- As usual, briefly describe each system of inequality.
Who are included, what is unequally distributed, who are
advantaged or disadvantaged, and the like. If you are
going to consider a subset of a larger system of inequality,
be clear about what you are doing and why.
- (OPTIONAL – To go further ... To
seek a more complete means of assessing experience, double
the examples, to consider two systems in which you have
experienced low standing and two in which you have had
higher standing, again representing both status inequality
and positional inequality if possible. This will give
you much more traction for seeing generalization
possibilities, but the time requirements may be more than
you can manage.)
- For each of these systems of inequality, try to characterize,
briefly, how those in
high-status locations have different experiences than those in
low-status locations. This is not easy to do
well. Among other things, note that it is rarely obvious
which kinds of experiences matter more and it is difficult to
reduce the varieties of experience into a few categories that are
not arbitrary.
- Focus on typical or defining
experiences. While experience seems inherently
individualistic because it is to such a degree private and
internal, the goal here is to move beyond the individual.
Systems of social inequality are comprised of socially organized
"structures," processes, and cultural understandings. In the
search of a social analysis of inequality, we are looking for
common or shared experiences (understanding that these may be
shared unequally, so that there are alternative experiences common
to subgroups determined by other conditions, circumstance, or even
random variation). A good way to start is by thinking about
typical experience.
- To make this effort more systematic and comparable, while trying
to assess differences in experience, here are dimensions you
might consider:
- How much and in what ways do people recognize the inequality
and think about it? For example, people may
- grasp the outlines of social inequality between groups
or positions
- see themselves as being in unequal relationships, but
not have a conception of this as part of a larger pattern
of inequality (e.g., when women or men see themselves as
superior or inferior to the other sex, but do not perceive
there to be gender inequality)
- people may not be able to conceptualize their experience
of an inequality as being inequality, but think of it in
different terms (e.g., believing it is not that "they" are
inferior or that "we" discriminate against "them," "they"
are just different)
- in what way do people seem to perceive or talk about
fairness with respect to an inequality?
- what sense of fairness do they have in their own
position?
- and how do they think about the fairness of the
existence of inequality (of this sort)?
- how do the advantaged and disadvantaged have distinctive
experiences about what other people who share their standing
are like?
- do the reference groups have different demographic
compositions (e.g. sex, ethnicity, age, class) apart from
the defining distinctions due to that inequality?
- are their cultural differences in the ways people dress,
ways of talking, leisure activities, religiosity, or the
like?
- how do people perceive those at their level as different
from those at the other end of the inequality spectrum, and
how do they interact differently with them?
- In particular, what, if any, are the common patterns of
deference when interacting with a previously unknown
person at the other end of the inequality spectrum?
(Most importantly, presumably, within the
institutional context embracing this form of inequality,
but also, potentially, in external contexts.)
- How do advantaged and disadvantaged people differ in general
ways that they experience the possibilities and realities of
life?
- how do people experience ambition vs.
resignation?;
- how do they differ in expectations for the future?
- do they allocate blame for failures and credit for
successes (of the individual) differently?
- do they have different orientations toward behavioral
tendencies such as violence, intimidation, manipulation,
cooperation, and subservience?
- are there significant differences in religiosity?
- do they seem to feel different loyalties toward the
institution surrounding the structure of inequality,
toward those in a similar location in the inequality
structure, toward those at a different level?
- how do they differ in their trust in authority and
government?
- If you can, consider the implications of social mobility or
changing social standing for these experiences of
inequalities. That is, do people differ in their
experience of a location in a system of inequality depending
on how they got there?
- Note that even people distinguished by locations in a
system of status inequalities may experience some form of
mobility. First, they may experience a shift in the
relative weight of the status inequality due to changes in
other status investing characteristics; an example
could be different meaning of race for affluent
blacks vs. poor blacks and affluent whites vs. poor
whites, where the analytical class difference may be
experience in terms of race. Second, the standing of
an entire status group or category may change over time;
consider, for example, the changes that have been seen by
middle-age blacks and whites in South Africa or women and
men in many countries.
- Note that someone whose status appears unchanged may
experience it differently because the statuses of
significant others do change
- How do people differ in their experiences of being
advantaged or disadvantaged in the referent form of inequality
depending on their location in other important forms of
inequality? (For example, how does the experience of
being Native American differ between the highly educated and
the low educated?)
- In short, the goal of this task is to contrast the
experiences of being advantaged with those of being disadvantaged
under two different kinds of inequality. The goal is to
examine these differences systematically, and to consider their
causes and their consequences.
- Finally, after completing work on the issues above,
considering the patterns of similarities and dissimilarities you
have discussed, can you devise any general hypotheses about the
experience of inequalities? That is, from the specific
patterns of differences you observe in your cases, what general
differences might you expect to find in other inequalities, in the
experiences of inequality, and in the causes and effects of those
experiences?
- Common Readings
- Recommended
Readings
- Michael Schwalbe, et al., "Generic
Processes in the Reproduction of Inequality: An Interactionist
Analysis," Social Forces, Vol. 79, No. 2 (Dec.,
2000), pp. 419-452 [jstor: 2675505]
- Alan B. Krueger –
Inequality, Too Much of a Good Thing (2003) [Grusky -
Contemporary]
- Arlie Russell Hochschild. "The
Time Bind." WorkingUSA. 1:2 (1997): 21-29.
[doi: 10.1111/j.1743-4580.1997.tb00019.x]
- Jerry Jacobs & Kathleen Gerson –
The Time Divide (2004) [Grusky – Contemporary]
- Douglas Hartmann. "An
Empirical Assessment of Whiteness Theory: Hidden from How Many?"
Social Problems August 2009, Vol. 56, No. 3:
403-24 [doi: 10.1525/sp.2009.56.3.403]
- Tak Wing Chan and John H. Goldthorpe –
The Social Stratification of Theatre, Dance, and Cinema
Attendance (2005) [Grusky – Contemporary]
- Robin Leidner, "Serving
Hamburgers and Selling Insurance: Gender, Work, and Identity in
Interactive Service Jobs," Gender and Society, Vol.
5, No. 2 (Jun., 1991), pp. 154-177 [jstor: 189482]
- Jeffrey Pfeffer and Nancy Langton, "The
Effect of Wage Dispersion on Satisfaction, Productivity, and
Working Collaboratively: Evidence from College and University
Faculty," Administrative Science Quarterly, Vol. 38,
No. 3 (Sep., 1993), pp. 382-407 [jstor: 2393373]
- James R. Kluegel and Eliot R. Smith, "Whites'
Beliefs about Blacks' Opportunity," American
Sociological Review, Vol. 47, No. 4 (Aug., 1982), pp.
518-532 [jstor: 2095196]
- Heli Vaaranen, "The
Emotional Experience of Class: Interpreting Working-Class Kids'
Street Racing in Helsinki," Annals of the American
Academy of Political and Social Science, Vol. 595, (Sep.,
2004), pp. 91-107 [jstor: 4127612]
- Related
Readings
VIII. How should we conceive interests in the
analysis of inequality?
Almost everyone analyzing any system of inequality refers
to "interests" sooner or later, even authors who emphasize cultural
or normative explanations. Yet, interests usually receive casual,
unsystematic treatment. This casual reliance on interests builds on
two simple assumptions: (1) a range of relevant potential actions and
events will have differential consequences for people depending on their
location in a system of inequality and (2) anticipation or past
experiences of these consequences will influence peoples' actions.
From this starting point the considerations of interests take many routes,
considering objective and subjective interests, individual versus
collective interests, realistic compared to misconceived interests,
consistent versus inconsistent interests, contradictory and ambiguous
interests, and so on. Simply put, every theory of inequality relies
on a theory of interests (even if a negative theory).
- Analytical
Task
- Analytical task: Interests
- Select two examples of inequality; if possible, use one example
of positional inequality and one of status inequality.
- Characterize who are the advantaged and who are the
disadvantaged in each example
- As always, specify clearly what is unequal
- If an example is not itself a system of inequality, but a
subsystem, a site where the effects of a system of inequality
are played out, or an intersection between systems of
inequality, then be clear what the relevant system or systems
of inequality might be
- For each example, examine the interests that seem to be
determined by the social organization of inequality, regardless
how people recognize them.
- List the most important ways that the "objective" interests
of the advantaged are at odds with those of the
disadvantaged; here the objective interests means the
interests implied by the structure of inequality and their
location within this structure, regardless of their
recognition of the interests
- Similarly, list the most important ways that the "objective"
interests of advantaged people or groups converge with
those of the disadvantaged. Here we are concerned with
interests related to conditions or practices that have a
widespread influence, usually where both the advantaged and
disadvantaged are exposed to common effects. For example,
potentially a shared interest between officials of an
autocratic government and the citizenry in maintaining public
peace would be relevant, but parallel or similar interests in
being healthy would not. Similarly, the employers and
workers in a corporation may have divided interests about the
distribution of the company's income, but they have convergent
interests in the corporation being successful.
- For the above assessments, both the interests at odds and
those that converge, consider whether the objective interests
seem try to characterize the most important interests in terms
of their clarity, consistency, extremity, and the like.
thinking about objective interests not as an individual
experiences them, but as they are produced and sustained by
the systems of inequality, how would you ?
- Now, a really tough part. As best you can, with these
examples, consider how interests become recognized or conceived
by people who are subject to the interest-producing circumstances
of inequality.
- We want to avoid the temptation to think about this in terms
of the reasons an individual might choose one way or
another. Instead, we want to examine how the
characteristics of objective interests or the structure of the
relevant inequality induces people to interpret their
interests in one way or another. We are seeking the
social conditions or dynamics that direct the conception of
interests.
- Note to begin that people may conceive their interests as
some subset of the objective interests previously identified,
or they may rely on conceptions that ignore or even oppose the
objective interests.
- What institutional and cultural processes or arrangements
seem to influence the emergence of common interests based on
the inequalities in your examples? E.g., the aged
or young adults may have a strong, self-conscious sense of
common interests under some circumstances but at other times
not recognize possible shared interests.; what determines when
they do see their concerns as common interests? Given
the objective interests you have identified, think under what
conditions you would expect people more likely to identify and
pursue each of those objective interests as opposed to the
conditions under which they would not do so. Similarly,
consider under what conditions people might be prone to
misinterpret their interests entirely. Or, under what
conditions they are more likely to stress oppositional
interests and under what conditions they will emphasize the
interests they have in common with those with whom they are
unequal?
- For each example, in what important ways and under what
circumstances do people's conceived interests seem to diverge
from their objective interests? (A classic example
occurs when members of a group, such as the working class,
believe their interests are best served by a political party
that is actually committed to policies that threaten their
interests, such as those typically associated with
Republicans.) What seems to account for the
disjunctions? (Consider both the advantaged and the
disadvantaged.)
- For the inequalities you are using, when and where do individual
interests seem to contradict collective interests? What
consequences does this have? (E.g., it is generally
in students' collective interest that professors grade all
students the same way, but tall, pretty boys have individual
interests in biased grading if professors favor tall, pretty
boys.)
- In short, the goal here is to develop some initial
ideas about the ways that interests work. We use two
examples as the simplest design that allows us to begin
generalizing about inequality, rather than describing the
character of a single instance. Using the chosen examples,
we want to produce some initial ideas about the range of objective
interests, both oppositional and shared, created by an inequality
system. Then we want to ask how people's conceptions of
their interests arise out of those objective interests in
interaction with impinging social conditions. And, in
particular we want to consider how and why conceived interests
might diverge from or even become inconsistent with objective
interests.
- Common Readings
- Johan Heilbron;
Interest: History of the Concept, International Encyclopedia
of the Social & Behavioral Sciences, 2004, Pages 7708-7712 [doi:
10.1016/B0-08-043076-7/00136-4]
- Richard Swedberg; "Can
There Be a Sociological Concept of Interest?"; Theory and
Society, vol. 34, no. 4, pp. 359-390, Aug 2005 [doi:
10.1007/s11186-005-1986-3]
- Robert Max Jackson, The Formation of Craft labor Markets,
excerpts
on interest formation among workers and employers: 33-39,
72-77, 83-104, 182-185, 288-290, 300-301, 329-331.
- Robert Max Jackson, Destined for Equality, excerpts
on interests in general (264-68), women's vs. men's (175-79),
men's changing (221-231), and those of the state & powerful men
(44-46, 67-70, 231-6)
- Raymond Boudon; "Action,
Theories of Social"; International Encyclopedia of the Social
& Behavioral Sciences, 2004, Pages 54-58 [doi:
10.1016/B0-08-043076-7/01819-2]
- Recommended
Readings
- James Madison, The
Federalist No. 10 ("The Utility of the Union as a
Safeguard Against Domestic Faction and Insurrection [continued]",
1787) & The
Federalist No. 51 ("The Structure of the Government
Must Furnish the Proper Checks and Balances Between the Different
Departments", 1788)
- Aage B. Sorensen; The "Structural
Basis of Social Inequality" The American Journal of
Sociology, Vol. 101, No. 5 (Mar., 1996), pp. 1333-1365
[jstor: 2782357]
- Jack Barbalet. (2012). "Self-interest
and the theory of action." The British Journal of
Sociology, 63: 412429. [doi:
10.1111/j.1468-4446.2012.01417.x]
- Lisa Belkin. "The
Opt-Out Revolution." New York Times, October 26, 2003
- Heather Boushey – Are
Women Opting Out? CEPR Reports and Issue
Briefs 2005-36, Center for Economic and Policy Research, 2005
- J. A. W. Gunn; "'Interest
Will Not Lie': A Seventeenth-Century Political Maxim"; Journal
of the History of Ideas, Vol. 29, No. 4 (Oct. - Dec., 1968),
pp. 551-564 [jstor: 2708293]
- Joseph Heath, "Methodological
Individualism", The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy
(Spring 2009 Edition)
- Hardin, Russell, "The
Free Rider Problem", The Stanford Encyclopedia of
Philosophy (Fall 2008 Edition)
- Wikipedia, "Prisoner's
dilemma"
- Related
Readings
- Franz Traxler; "Business
Associations and Labor Unions in Comparison: Theoretical
Perspectives and Empirical Findings on Social Class, Collective
Action and Associational Organizability"; The British
Journal of Sociology, Vol. 44, No. 4 (Dec., 1993), pp.
673-691 [jstor: 591416]
- Erik Olin Wright; "Working-Class
Power, Capitalist-Class Interests, and Class Compromise"; The
American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 105, No. 4 (Jan., 2000),
pp. 957-1002 [jstor: 3003886]
- Dennis Chong; "Values
versus Interests in the Explanation of Social Conflict"; University
of Pennsylvania Law Review, Vol. 144, No. 5 (May, 1996), pp.
2079-2134 [jstor: 3312649]
- Catherine I. Bolzendahl, Daniel J. Myers; "Feminist
Attitudes and Support for Gender Equality: Opinion Change in
Women and Men, 1974-1998"; Social Forces, Vol. 83,
No. 2 (Dec., 2004), pp. 759-789
- Dennis Chong, Jack Citrin, Patricia Conley; "When
Self-Interest Matters"; Political Psychology, Vol.
22, No. 3 (Sep., 2001), pp. 541-570 [doi: 10.1111/0162-895X.00253]
- Mustafa Emirbayer, Ann Mische; "What
Is Agency?"; The American Journal of Sociology, Vol.
103, No. 4 (Jan., 1998), pp. 962-1023 [read quickly – to
read slowly is to risk calcification of the intellect] [jstor:
2782934]
- ...
IX. What determines the allocation of people (or
other relevant unit) within a positional system of inequality?
This issue includes questions commonly addressed in the literatures
on social mobility and status attainment (and on placement within
organizations). More or less independent of its occupants, a system
of positional inequality has a static
"structure" characterized by the direct relationships of
authority and dependence between positions; the ranking of
positions according to the rewards, authority, opportunities, and statuses
attached to them; and the demographic profile defined by the number of
positions of each type. A positional inequality system also has a dynamic
structure defined by the movement of people through it, both
within careers and between generations. These two components of
structure – the static and the dynamic – are linked by the selection
processes controlling access to positions. We can usefully conceive
positional inequality as the juxtaposition of two parallel systems that
are often confused or conflated: first, the structure of relationships
among the positions constituting the system of inequality (e.g., the
enduring authority relationship between a managerial position and a
line-worker position), and, second, the relations between the people who
occupy these positions (e.g., the interactions between managers and
workers). The patterns of people's movement between positions both
reflects and influences the relationships among positions, but it also
shows the impact of impinging status inequalities. To understand the
inequalities among people, we obviously need to understand what decides
which people occupy which positions.
- Analytical
Task
- Analytical task: We will explore how positional
inequalities work. Recall that two general examples of positional
inequalities would be the occupational structure of a modern
society or the hierarchy of positions within a complex
organization. Note that, in this analytical context, income
inequality is an effect of positional inequalities;
income inequality is not itself a system of inequality
(involving neither transferable positions nor status groups),
although it functions as both an incentive and consequence of
positional (and status) inequalities. Also note that positional
inequalities are commonly constituted by relatively clear "local"
hierarchies that only loosely translate into a societal wide
hierarchy. For example, complex organizations usually have
well-defined positional hierarchies, but their finer distinctions
are organization or industry specific. As a result, people
(both scholars and ordinary people) use common characteristics of
positions – such as income, authority level, or organizational
size – to translate "local" positional standings into a comparable
metric.
- Choose two dissimilar examples of positional inequalities.
Try to choose two that have different institutional settings, are
not closely causally connected to each other, or operate by
different logics. They may coexist in one society or be
drawn from different (in space or time) societies.
- For each example, describe the overall structure of
positions. Among other things, an analytical description of
a positional structure should consider the following:
- Assess the differential characteristics attached to the
positions (rewards, authority, visibility, etc.)
- Summarize and characterize the relationships among
positions.
- Consider the simple demographics of the system: how many
positions exist at each level?; what is the turnover rate of
personnel occupying the positions (the departure rates)?; how
stable is the demographic profile (i.e., do the relative and
absolute numbers remain the same over time)?
- If possible to assess, how did the existing configuration of
positions come into existence?
- For each example, try to describe the "normal" pathways of
movement into and between positions
- What are the typical initial entry points, the positions
that take people who have not previously been in the system of
positional inequality? For example, in a large business
or organization, many positions are typically filled by
promotions from other positions; people are not usually hired
from the outside for such positions. Commonly, a If these entry-point
positions are themselves unequal, also consider
- How are the entry points unequal ?
- What determines who gets in which ones?
- Who controls the allocation process of the initial
positions (directly and indirectly)?
- What is the pattern of movement among positions within the
system?
- To what degree does selectivity operate (the demographic
constraint)? (Among other things, this asks what
proportion of people at any given level will ascend to a
higher level.)
- Consider if lateral movement among positions is relevant
to hierarchical movement.
- Is there significant downward movement as well as upward
in the positional hierarchy? If so, remember
to examine downward as well as upward for all issues about
movement among positions.
- What appears to decide who moves up into more desirable
positions (or down)?
- Is the determining process fairly consistent across
positions or does it vary by how high or in what
sector the position appears?
- who has decision-making power?
- how standardized or impartial are the processes
governing mobility among positions? Note that
impartiality can be the result of self-conscious
efforts to eliminate bias and reliance on
inappropriate criteria, but, alternatively, it also
can be the result of an uncontrolled process that is
inherently unbiased (as some would suggest for market
mechanisms)? Slave traders, for example, may be
just as impartial toward the ethnic divisions among
their chattel as the most progressive advocate of
meritocratic assessments.
- How is the position-allocation process ideologically
conceived?;
- particularly consider ideological constructs that
reinforce, obfuscate, legitimate, or challenge the
allocation process.
- how are "success" and "failure" conceived (as moral and
practical categories)
- are there competing ideological formulations of what
causes success and failure?
- Taking into account all the above, comparing the two examples,
what can you say about the patterns of affiliation, alliance,
deference, patronage, avoidance, opposition, and conflict that
constitute the structure of relationships among people occupying
different locations in a positional inequality? While
exploring this issue, pay careful attention to the distinction
between the positions and the people occupying them.
- In short, the goal of this task is to gain some insight
into the ways that positional systems of inequality work.
Using two concrete examples is the simplest possible design for
identifying some of the common characteristics of such
systems. A commonly unanticipated difficulty in analyzing
such systems arises from their duality: a structure of
relationships among the positions independent of the people who
occupy them and the dynamics of relationships among the people who
do occupy the positions.
- Common Readings
- Recommended
Readings
- J. Schumpeter,
"Social Classes in an Ethnically Homogeneous Environment."
(1927) In
Imperialism and Social Classes. (read from
beginning through the first section of "Summary and
Conclusions", ignore the last few pages) [a brilliant, albeit
flawed, analysis of class]
- DiPrete, Thomas
A. and Gregory M. Eirich. "Cumulative
advantage as a mechanism for inequality: A review of
theoretical and empirical developments." Annual
Review of Sociology, 32 (2006): 271-297
[doi: 10.1146/annurev.soc.32.061604.123127]
- Aaron M., Jennings,
Jennifer L. "Cumulative
Knowledge about Cumulative Advantage". Swiss Journal
of Sociology, 2009, Vol. 35 Issue 2, pp. 211-229
- Maria Charles. "A
World of Difference: International Trends in Women's
Economic Status." Annual Review of Sociology. Vol.
37 (2011): 355-371 [doi:
10.1146/annurev.soc.012809.102548]
- Peter B Doeringer & Michael J. Piore. "Unemployment
and the Dual Labor Market." Public Interest.
38 (1975: Winter): 67-79.
- Gary Solon. "Intergenerational
Income Mobility." The American Economic Review.
Vol. 82, No. 3 (Jun., 1992), pp. 393-408. [jstor: 2117312]
- Rachel A. Rosenfeld "Job
Mobility and Career Processes"; Annual Review of
Sociology, Vol. 18, (1992), pp. 39-61 [jstor: 2083445]
- Robert P. Althauser; "Internal
Labor Markets"; Annual Review of Sociology, Vol. 15, (1989),
pp. 143-161 [jstor: 2083222]
- Douglas S. Massey. "American
Apartheid: Segregation and the Making of the Underclass." American
Journal of Sociology 96(2) (Sep 1990): 329-357. [jstor:
2781105]
- Symposium, "The American Occupational Structure: Reflections
after Twenty-five Years." Contemporary Sociology 21 (1992):
596-668. [varied commentators try to makes sense of 25 years of
social mobility research]
- Treiman, Donald J., and Harry B. G. Ganzeboom. "The
Fourth Generation of Comparative Stratification Research."
In The International Handbook
of Sociology, edited by Stella R. Quah and Arnaud Sales,
123-51. London: SAGE Publications Ltd., 2000. [doi:
10.4135/9781848608405.n6]
- Adrian E. Raftery and Michael Hout. "Maximally
Maintained Inequality: Expansion, Reform, and Opportunity in
Irish Education,1921-75." Sociology
of Education, Vol. 66, No. 1 (Jan., 1993), pp. 41-62.
[jstor: 2112784]
- William H. Sewell, Archibald 0. Haller, and Alejandro Portes –
The Educational and Early Occupational Attainment Process
(1969) [Grusky – Classic]
- Mark S. Granovetter. "The
Strength of Weak Ties." American Journal of Sociology,
Vol. 78, No. 6 (May, 1973), pp. 1360-1380. [jstor: 2776392]
- Nan Lin –
Social Networks and Status Attainment (1999) [Grusky -
Contemporary]
- Paul DiMaggio and Filiz Garip. "Network
Effects and Social Inequality." Annual Review of Sociology.
Vol. 38 (2012): 93-118. [doi: 10.1146/annurev.soc.012809.102545]
- Ronald S. Burt –
Structural Holes (1997) [Grusky – Contemporary]
- Dalton Conley –
The Pecking Order, Which Siblings Succeed and Why?
(2004) [Grusky – Contemporary]
- Robert Gibbons, Michael Waldman; "A
Theory of Wage and Promotion Dynamics Inside Firms;" Quarterly
Journal of Economics November 1999, Vol. 114, No. 4:
1321-1358. [doi: 10.1162/003355399556287]
- Related
Readings
- Ivan D. Chase. "Vacancy
Chains." Annual Review of Sociology. (1991) Vol.
17: 133-154. [doi: 10.1146/annurev.so.17.080191.001025]
- Christopher Jencks. "Inequality
in Retrospect." Harvard Educational Review. 43(1) (Spring
1973): 138-164.
- Christopher Jencks, Lauri Perman and Lee Rainwater. "What
Is a Good Job? A New Measure of Labor-Market Success." American
Journal of Sociology. Vol. 93, No. 6, May, 1988.
[jstor: 2780816]
- Emily Beller and Michael Hout. "Intergenerational
Social Mobility: The United States in Comparative Perspective."
The Future of Children.
Vol 16 N 2 (Fall 2006): 19-36
- Thomas J. Dohmen, Ben Kriechel and Gerard A. Pfann; "Monkey
Bars and Ladders: The Importance of Lateral and Vertical Job
Mobility in Internal Labor Market Careers"; Journal of
Population Economics, Vol. 17, No. 2 (Jun., 2004), pp.
193-228 [doi: 10.1007/s00148-004-0191-4f]
- Joseph P. Ferrie; "History
Lessons: The End of American Exceptionalism? Mobility in the
United States since 1850"; The Journal of Economic
Perspectives, Vol. 19, No. 3 (Summer, 2005), pp.
199-215 [doi: 10.1257/089533005774357824]
- ...
X. What are the bases of actions that secure dominance
over time?
From those enjoying the most privileged positions to those suffering the
most disadvantages, people may believe that the system of inequality that
divides them reflects the elusively differential favor of the gods, the
cruel fate of nature's uneven treatment, or unavoidable results of
people's differential efforts and capacities. In truth, systems of
inequality require work to keep them going, particularly the efforts of
those in superior positions to preserve the shape of the system and their
positions within it. We cannot hope to grasp the logic of a system
of inequality until we understand what this work is and how it gets done.
- Analytical
Task
- Analytical task: Assess how and why advantaged
people (or their agents) act in ways that (1) preserve their
advantages and (2) preserve the system of inequality that gives
them advantages.
- Select two examples of inequality to assess the actions of
advantaged people. The first example should concern gender
inequality – this may be an instance of gender inequality (e.g.,
gender inequality in an organization, or in an occupation, or in a
sport) or it may be gender inequality more generally (although
this may prove more difficult). The second example should be
a different kind of inequality, preferably an example of
positional inequality or alternatively an example of a quite
different form of status inequality.
- For each example of inequality, the goal is to identify and
explain the kinds of actions by advantaged people that (1) seem to
occur consistently and (2) seem to reinforce their
advantages. To approach this problem systematically, try to
answer the following about each example of inequality:
- How do the advantaged people treat disadvantaged people in
direct interactions; the relevant comparisons are with the
ways the advantaged relate to each other and the ways the
disadvantaged relate to each other?
- How do advantaged people have different kinds of
relationships with other advantaged people than than they have
with disadvantaged people (this is similar to the previous,
but concerns the more general problem of relationships
rather than interactions)?
- In what ways might common actions or behavioral patterns of
those in the advantaged "class" – actions that use or reflect
their advantaged circumstances – reinforce the privileges of
advantaged people, even though the actions are not aimed at
disadvantaged people or at sustaining inequality? (For
example, the advantaged might buy all unused land for golf
courses and expansive estates, leaving poor farmers no way to
expand their acreage for crops.)
- How do advantaged people respond if one of them is
challenged by a disadvantaged person.
- "Challenges" can take many forms. A member of a
subordinate group may simply refuse to show "proper"
deference, as when a lower caste person does not step
aside, a black woman does not go to her place in the rear
of a bus, or a member of the secretarial pool addresses
managers by their first name just as they do her.
Someone with lower standing may adopt the dress or
mannerisms of those with higher standing, or attempt to
move into their neighborhoods or schools. More
directly, someone with lower standing may reject and defy
efforts to exercise authority by those "above" them.
And so forth ....
- Consider not only the actions of the person who is
directly challenged, but potential actions by others in
the advantaged class.
- How do advantaged people exercise power in government, over
laws, or in the economy in ways that benefit those with
advantages?
- How do advantaged people respond if there is a collective
challenge to the system of inequality in which they have
advantages?
- Looking over the range of actions you identify as relevant
above, can they usefully be categorized? For example, one
might divide them into those that mainly benefit an individual's
status and those that mainly help sustain the system of
inequality. The goal here is to consider if there is an
analytically useful way to reduce the range of relevant actions
and behavior patterns into a small number of general types.
- What within the system of inequality seems to organize and
ensure the actions that sustain it? For example, in the
simplest conceivable system of inequality, we might find the only
mechanism is the interests of those in dominance – they
individually act on those interests in a manner unmediated
by ideology, norms, relationships with others in the dominant
group, laws, organizational processes, or anything else.
More complex systems involve mechanisms that induce these actions,
giving individuals motivation, direction, and support.
Looking at the range of actions identified as relevant, what stand
out as the mechanisms that make such actions consistent and
effective?
- What seem to be important limitations on the actions that secure
dominance? How are these actions constrained by laws, norms,
ideology, resources, or the like? What conditions or
potentials for the future might cause the actions to lose
enthusiasm or effectiveness?
- In short, this task concerns the ways that inequality
systems induce advantaged groups to act in ways that sustain the
inequality (and their standing within that inequality). Once
again, using two examples is the simplest design to allow initial
speculations about the general functioning of inequality.
The questions above aim to help one to think systematically about
the range of possible actions and their sources.
- When analyzing the actions of the advantaged (and
disadvantaged) as described above, keeping several considerations
in mind may help:
- The shorthand references here to "the actions of advantaged
people" do not imply that all advantaged people act the same
way or that the actions that sustain inequality are produced
in the same way and at the same rate by all the
advantaged. Such actions may be nearly universal, they
may be typical but with a high degree of variation
across people and circumstances, or they may be the special
actions of a minority who are the key representatives of the
group interests.
- The analytical focus should be on the processes and
circumstances that induce enough actions of sufficient
effectiveness by enough advantaged people to protect the
inequality system. An individualistic focus on the
motives or beliefs of people will probably go astray.
- Note initially that the relevant actions of the advantaged
may differ from those of the disadvantaged in varied ways
other than reflecting divergent interests. For example,
(1) the opportunities to act may differ (e.g. differential
access to higher education), (2) analogous actions may
have different effects, and (3) even with equivalent
opportunities and effects, they may choose to act differently
(e.g. because they have different beliefs or respond to
different interests).
- Common Readings
- C. Wright Mills –
The Power Elite (1956) [Grusky – Classic]
- Melvin Oliver and Thomas M. Shapiro –
Black Wealth/White Wealth: A New Perspective on Racial Inequality
(1997) [Grusky – Contemporary]
- Gaetano Mosca – The
Ruling Class (excerpt) (1897)
- Michael Schwalbe; "The
Elements of Inequality"; Contemporary Sociology, vol.
29, no. 6, pp. 775-781, Nov 2000 [jstor: 2654084]
- Barbara F. Reskin; "Including
Mechanisms in Our Models of Ascriptive Inequality"; American
Sociological Review, Vol. 68, No. 1 (Feb., 2003), pp. 1-21
[jstor: 3088900]
- Cecilia Ridgeway. Ch. 1, "
The Puzzle of Persistence", in Framed by Gender, How
Gender Inequality Persists in the Modern World, (2011) Oxford
Univ. Press. [doi: 10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199755776.003.0001]
- On Tilly's Durable Inequality (1999) argument:
- Erik Olin Wright; "Metatheoretical
Foundations of Charles Tilly's Durable Inequality;"
Comparative Studies in Society and History, Vol. 42, No.
2 (Apr., 2000), pp. 458-474 [For our immediate purposes,
read this mainly to understand what Tilly was doing in Durable
Inequality. The following two short pieces by Tilly
convey his point of view.] [jstor: 2696613]
- Charles Tilly; "Changing
Forms of Inequality"; Sociological Theory, Vol.
21, No. 1 (Mar., 2003), pp. 31-36 [jstor: 3108606]
- Charles Tilly; "Relational
Studies of Inequality"; Contemporary Sociology,
Vol. 29, No. 6 (Nov., 2000), pp. 782-785 [jstor: 2654085]
- Jerome Karabel. "Status-Group
Struggle, Organizational Interests, and the Limits of
Institutional Autonomy: The Transformation of Harvard, Yale, and
Princeton, 1918-1940." Theory and Society, Vol. 13,
No. 1 (Jan., 1984), pp. 1-40 [jstor: 657163]
- Recommended
Readings
- Marianne Bertrand and Sendhil Mullainathan. "Are
Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal? A Field
Experiment on Labor Market Discrimination." The
American Economic Review, 94(4): 991-1013. [doi:
10.1257/0002828042002561]
- Ralph H. Turner –
Sponsored and Contest Mobility and the School System
[Grusky – Classic]
- David L. Swartz. "Social
Closure in American Elite Higher Education." Theory and
Society Vol. 37, No. 4 (Aug., 2008), pp. 409-419.
[doi: 10.1007/s11186-008-9064-2]
- Nicholas Petryszak; "The
Dynamics of Acquiescence in South Africa"; African
Affairs, Vol. 75, No. 301 (Oct., 1976), pp. 444-462 [jstor:
721264]
- Claude Steele –
Stereotype Threat and African-American Student Achievement
[Grusky – Contemporary]
- Joe R. Feagin. "The
Continuing Significance of Race: Antiblack Discrimination in
Public Places." American
Sociological Review Vol. 56, No. 1 (Feb., 1991) (pp.
101-116) [jstor: 2095676] & "Toward
an Integrated Theory of Systemic Racism." Pp. 203-223 in
Krysan, Maria and Lewis, Amanda E. The
Changing Terrain of Race and Ethnicity 2004.
- Related
Readings
XI. What induces reducing or overcoming inequalities?
Inequality systems do not only have causes that bring them into
existence and causes that preserve them, they also have causes that
potentially reduce or eliminate them. Systems of inequality
may decline because they are pushed out of the way by new systems of
inequality, because they simply become increasingly ineffective or
irrelevant, because the disadvantaged are increasingly able to overcome
their circumstances as individuals, or because the system is dramatically
overturned by collective actions from below or intrusion from
invaders. How and why these processes dilute, undermine, or
eliminate inequalities is theoretically underdeveloped.
- Analytical
Task
- Analytical task: Declining inequalities
- Select as example of social inequality, positional or status,
that showed significant reductions in the degree of inequality
over time.
- For the selected example of inequality, if it is not a
system of inequality but a component, result, or instance of a
system of inequality, the analysis should include careful
consideration of the system itself.
- (Note that inequality may decline in a component as a result
of overall decline in the system, decline in a component may
induce greater inequality in the system, or decline in a
component may take place independently of and without
noticeable impact of the enveloping system.
- In what ways did those involved in the example of inequality
being considered actively promote or resist its
decline?
- In our simplest examples, "those involved" reduces to the
advantaged group versus the disadvantaged. In real life,
seems can be much more complex. Each system of
inequality may have multiple types of involvement,
distinguished by subtle or ambiguous differences of interests,
relationships and activities. And, systems of inequality
overlap and interact. We want to be sensitive to this
potential complexity, but willing to reduce it conceptually as
far as possible to produce a manageable model.
- Note that people may actively promote or resist a change in
inequality for motives that are not focused on the issue of
the inequality's persistence.
- The goal here is to characterize the types of people whose
actions tended to reinforce the inequality and those whose
actions tended to erode it. Recall that members of
advantaged groups may join the challengers (against their
putative interests) and members of the disadvantaged may join
the supporters.
- Were any other coexisting systems of inequality declining or
becoming more extreme during the same period? If so, is it
possible to identify causal processes that might connect the
simultaneous changes?
- Were there direct clashes over the competing interests of those
advantaged and those disadvantaged by system of inequality that
was declining? If so, what were there causes and their
consequences?
- Were there any independent changes in the circumstances of the
advantaged people that plausibly diminished their will or ability
to sustain the pattern of inequality?
- Were actors who were not direct participants in the systems of
inequality (i.e. not acting as members of the advantaged or
disadvantaged) significant for promoting or obstructing the
movement toward change? The state is an obvious contender
here, but so are others whose interests or symbolic commitments
seem to be at stake.
- Are there other processes, actors, circumstances, or causal
dynamics neglected by the above questions that seem important to
analyzing the changes in inequality in the examples being
considered?
- In short, the goal this week is to explore the
conditions and processes that work against the persistence of
inequalities under appropriate structural and historical
circumstances.
- Common Readings
- Karl Marx's theories of capitalism and societal transformation,
often simplified as the theory of historical materialism, is a
benchmark of all later theories aiming to explain changing systems
of inequality. The ideas are developed throughout his
work. Here are a couple non-scholarly, but reasonable,
introductions.
- T. H. Marshall. "Citizenship
and Social Class." (1949) Excerpt.
- Robert Max Jackson; "Opposing
Forces: How, Why, and When Will Gender Inequality Disappear?";
in Declining Significance of Gender (eds. Francine D. Blau,
Mary C. Brinton, David B. Grusky) 2006. (But compare Ridgeway
in previous topic.)
- A. de Toqueville, "Relations
of Masters and Servants." (From Democracy
in America, v. 2, 1840)
- William Julius Wilson.
"The Declining Significance of Race." Society. 15:2
(1978): 56-62. [doi: 10.1007/BF03181003] (This summarizes the
arguments in Wilson's book of the same name. The book merits
reading in full.)
- See reviews of James C. Scott's book, Domination and the Arts
of Resistance in AJS
and Contemporary
Soc.
- Recommended
Readings
- Jens Beckert; "The
Longue Durée of Inheritance Law. Discourses and
Institutional Development in France, Germany, and the United
States since 1800"; Archives Europeennes de
Sociologie/European Journal of Sociology, vol. 48, no. 1,
pp. 79-120, 2007 [This contains the central argument of the book
that is discussed in the symposium listed next.]
- Erik Olin Wright. "The
Shadow of Exploitation in Weber's Class Analysis." American
Sociological Review.
Vol. 67, No. 6, (Dec., 2002) : 832-53. [jstor: 3088972]
- Marco H.D. van Leeuwen and Ineke Maas. "Historical
Studies of Social Mobility and Stratification." Annual
Review of Sociology. 2010. 36:42951. [doi:
10.1146/annurev.soc.012809.10263]
- Alejandro Portes and Min Zhou –
The New Second Generation: Segmented Assimilation and Its
Variants (1993) [Grusky – Contemporary]
- Blau, Francine D., and Lawrence M. Kahn. 2000. "Gender
Differences in Pay." Journal of Economic Perspectives,
14(4): 75-99. [doi: 10.1257/jep.14.4.75]
- Blau, Francine D.; Kahn, Lawrence M. "The
Gender Pay Gap: Have Women Gone as Far as They Can?"
Academy of Management Perspectives. Feb 2007, 21(1): 7-23.
[doi: 10.5465/AMP.2007.24286161"]
- Martina Morris and Bruce Western. "Inequality
in Earnings: Trends and Implications." [Grusky -
Contemporary]
- Paula England; "Toward
Gender Equality: Progress and Bottlenecks"; in Declining
Significance of Gender; eds. Francine D. Blau, Mary C.
Brinton, David B. Grusky; 2006.
- Cecilia L. Ridgeway; "Gender
as an Organizing Force in Social Relations: Implications for the
Future of Inequality"; in Declining Significance of
Gender; eds. Francine D. Blau, Mary C. Brinton, David B.
Grusky; 2006.
- Related
Readings
XII. What are the theoretical and empirical
relationships between different forms of inequality?
Multiple systems of inequality coexist in societies, with crosscutting
categories and with individuals simultaneously located in each. An
older tradition in sociology suggested that the degree of overlap between
different forms of inequality was one condition influencing the likelihood
of class formation. A more recent interest has been the
"intersection" between race, gender, and class as experienced by
individuals, with the central (largely atheoretical) premise that the
implications of one's status in one system depends on one's statuses in
the others. Our concern here is more at the level of inequality's
organization, asking in what ways different systems of inequality interact
with each other.
- Analytical
Task
- Analytical task: Interdependence of inequalities
- Select one society and historical moment (or one period, such as
the second half of the 20th century). Within this
historical context, select two examples of systems of positional
inequality and two examples of systems of status inequality,
chosen such that a significant number of individuals will have a
location within each of the four systems considered. .
- Assess in what ways and to what degree an individual's status in
one instance of inequality relates to others. To be systematic,
consider
- How standing in one form of positional inequality relates to
standing in the other example of positional inequality
- How standing in one instance of status inequality relates to
standing in the other form of status inequality
- How standing in the systems of positional inequality relate
to standing in the systems of status inequality
- Assess how the organization and functioning of these systems of
inequality influence or overlap each other. Among other things,
this might include considering
- How the "locations" in the two examples of positional
inequality are related. Are any locations defined
simultaneously in both systems? Are there enduring
relationships between locations in the two systems that
continue regardless who are in those locations? Are there
sustained patterns of movement between the two systems?
- What relationships exist among the the symbolic
representations and ideological legitimation schemes
associated with the forms of inequality being examined?
Are they simply independent?; are they separate but drawing on
some common ideas?; are they partially or wholly merged into
one scheme that serves all at once?
- In what ways is persistence of one system of inequality
dependent on its relationship with another? For example, how
might the elimination of any one system of inequality affect
the others.?
- What links exist between the laws and governmental
mechanisms that support these systems of inequality?
- Can we identify inconsistencies or sources of friction
between these systems of inequality?
- How do historical developments and changes in these systems
relate to each other?
- Common Readings
- Jerry A. Jacobs. "Gender
Inequality and Higher Education." Annual Review of
Sociology, Vol. 22, (1996), pp. 153-185. Also see
reviews of Jacobs's 1989 Revolving
Doors: Sex Segregation and Women's Careers by Patricia
Roos, Christine
Williams, & James
Baron. [doi: 10.1146/annurev.soc.22.1.153"] [jstor: 2780519]
- Barbara F. Reskin –
Labor Markets as Queues: A Structural Approach to Changing
Occupational Sex Composition (1991) [Grusky -
Contemporary]
- Bruce Western –
Incarceration, Unemployment, and Inequality
[Grusky – Contemporary]
- Douglas S. Massey, Jonathan Rothwell, and Thurston Domina. "The
Changing Bases of Segregation in the United States." The
ANNALS of the American Academy of Political and Social Science
November 2009 626: 74-90, [doi: 10.1177/0002716209343558]
- Claude S. Fischer. "Showing
that Neighborhoods Matter." City
& Community, 12 (2013): 7?12. [doi: 10.1111/cico.12005]
- Recommended
Readings
- Peter M. Blau. "A
Fable about Social Structure." Social
Forces, Vol. 58, No. 3 (Mar., 1980), pp. 777-788.
On the importance of always considering the implications of
numbers. [jstor: 2577184]
- Jerry A. Jacobs. "Long-Term
Trends in Occupational Segregation by Sex." American
Journal of Sociology. Vol. 95, No. 1 (Jul., 1989):
160-173. [jstor: 2780409]
- Erik Olin Wright; "Race,
Class, and Income Inequality"; The American Journal of
Sociology, Vol. 83, No. 6 (May, 1978), pp. 1368-1397 [jstor:
2778109]
- Margaret L. Andersen; "Thinking
about Women: A Quarter Century's View"; Gender &
Society, vol. 19, no. 4, pp. 437-455, Aug 2005 [doi:
10.1177/0891243205276756]
- Michael Hout. "Social
and Economic Returns to College Education in the United States."
Annual Review of Sociology,
Vol. 38 (2012): 379-400 [doi: 10.1146/annurev.soc.012809.102503]
- Related
Readings
XIII. What causes inequality?
Perhaps the most fundamental question about inequalities, and sometimes
seeming the most illusive to answer, is the misleadingly simple question,
what causes inequality? While no general, all embracing answer is
possible (at this time), progress in understanding inequality demands that
we continually try to improve our analyses of the causes. Any effort
to do this must consider different forms of causation that are
possible.
- Analytical
Task
- Analytical task: We want to investigate what
causes inequalities. Causation is a difficult, often
elusive, concept. What we mean by the causes of inequalities
can take different forms. We can ask why it comes into
existence. This question about origins may concern the
specific historical circumstances or sequence of events in which
an inequality emerges. Or we might interpret original causes
in terms of the social conditions necessary for such inequality to
emerge or, somewhat differently, the social conditions that make
it unavoidable. We might instead ask what causes (or allows)
an inequality to persist over time, potentially distinct from the
reasons for its origin, the conditions and processes that sustain
it. Or, we might focus on the variations in the severity of
some inequality, seeking the key to understanding it in the
conditions that cause it to be great in some places and slight in
others. In either case, we may stress the mechanisms, the
recurring actions and social processes that produce the
inequality, or we may stress the conditions that allow or require
it. Given this expanse of possibilities, we must narrow our
question, to make it reasonable.
- Choose two kinds of inequality, each of which varies
considerably in its intensity. For each kind choose one
example that has low inequality and another that has high
inequality. These four examples, two with low inequality to
compare with two having high inequality, will be the basis of the
analysis. These may come from the same historical and
cultural setting or from different ones.
- For each kind of inequality, if it is not a system of
inequality but a component, result, or instance of a system of
inequality, the analysis should stress the system.
- For example, if we start with two unequal occupations, we
would say that they are in most cases not a system of
inequality but a part of one. So, we could shift our
attention to the system of occupational inequality. Or,
if we begin with the inequality between women and men within
the financial industry, we could move to the general
inequality between the sexes.
- In general, an example of inequality that is a component,
result, or instance of a system of inequality may have
particularistic causes that seem sufficient to account for its
contours or variations. However, we expect its existence
is derivative of the relevant system of inequality and that it
and other similar instances that are derivative of the same
system of inequality are all subject to the causal processes
that generate and sustain that system of inequality.
Thus, an effort to identify and make sense of the causal
processes cannot look at the component or instance alone.
- Describe each kind of inequality and the difference between the
higher and lower inequality instances.
- As always, describe who are distinguished by the inequality,
and what it is that is unequal.
- Specify why we consider the inequality in one instance to be
significantly higher than in the other. This is a
measurement issue on the surface, but commonly has deeper
implications about what the inequality means.
- Comparing the instances of high inequality with those of low
inequality, construct a series of hypotheses about about the
possible causes of high inequality (compared to low
inequality). In some cases these hypotheses may apply to
both kinds of inequality similarly while in others they are quite
different – try to be clear about this. For each
hypothesis, explain the reasoning behind your speculation.
In attempting to generate hypotheses representing a systematic
analysis, among other things to think about, you might consider:
- the origins of each example of inequality (e.g., do the high
and low inequality instances arise from distinctive conditions
that relate to their subsequent intensity)
- the history of changes in levels of inequality if applicable
and known (e.g., does knowledge of their varying intensities
over time suggest anything about why or how they differ in the
instances you compare?0
- political and legal contexts
- ideological and cultural contexts
- relationships to other forms of inequality
- direct relationships between those advantaged and those
disadvantaged by the inequality
- how individuals' statuses are decided
- ... Each of the foregoing refer to important aspects of an
inequality system that imply the existence of some causal
process. Looking back over the previous topics we have
examined should give more facets of inequality calling for a
similar causal analysis.
- Moving beyond hypotheses, see which of these more general
questions you can begin to answer.
- Consider to what degree the origins, the persistence, or the
severity of the inequality is explained by the outcomes of
self-interested actions of individuals and organizations.
- Consider to what degree the origins, the persistence, or the
severity of the inequality is explained by its functional and
structural relationships to important social arrangements or
"needs."
- Consider to what degree the origins, the persistence, or the
severity of the inequality is explained by some competitive
processes.
- Try to be self-conscious about the comparisons being made,
implicit or explicit, and what alternatives might be possible.
- Try not to forget that inequality induces processes,
conditions, and structures that limit resistance's
effectiveness and part of its explanation lies in the ways
this obstruction or resistance works.
- In short, our
analytical goal is to generate ideas about what produces
inequality, by first looking at what seems to explain variations
in the degree of severity of two types of inequality.
- Common Readings
- Kingsley Davis and Wilbert E. Moore. "Some
Principles of Stratification." American Sociological Review,
Vol. 10, No. 2, (Apr., 1945), pp. 242-249; also read:
- Peter M. Blau and Otis Dudley Duncan. (1967) "The
Process of Stratification." [Grusky – Classic]
- Roger V. Gould; "The
Origins of Status Hierarchies: A Formal Theory and Empirical Test";
The American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 107, No. 5
(Mar., 2002), pp. 1143-1178 [jstor: 3081318]
- Peter M. Blau; "The
Hierarchy of Authority in Organizations"; The American
Journal of Sociology, Vol. 73, No. 4 (Jan., 1968), pp. 453-467
[jstor: 2775943]
- Karl Marx and Frederick Engels. Manifesto of the Communist Party.
Not the analytical power of Capital,
but the most widely read statement. Look at Chapter 1 (pp.
15-21), Bourgeois and Proletarians, and the questions and answers in
pp. 37-54.
- Douglas S. Massey. "How Stratification Works." Ch 1 of Categorically
Unequal (2007). (Also might look at conclusion,
"America Unequal," Ch 7.)
- Recommended
Readings
- Karl Marx. "Marx
on Social Classes and Class Conflict." Relevant
excerpts from Marx's work.
- Ernest Mandel. "Marx,
Karl Heinrich (1818-1883)". The New Palgrave Dictionary
of Economic, Second Edition. Eds. Steven N. Durlauf and
Lawrence E. Blume. Palgrave Macmillan, [1987] 2008. (Knowledgeable
summary and defense of Marx's ideas.) [doi:
10.1057/9780230226203.1051]
- Robert C. Hauhart. "The
Davis-Moore Theory of Stratification: The Life Course of a
Socially Constructed Classic." The American Sociologist,
Vol. 34, No. 4 (Winter, 2003), pp. 5-24. [jstor: 27700363]
- W. Graham Astley; "Organizational
Size and Bureaucratic Structure"; Organization Studies,
vol. 6, no. 3, pp. 201-228, 1985 [doi: 10.1177/017084068500600301]
- Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez. "The
Evolution of Top Incomes: A Historical and International
Perspective." The American Economic Review, 96(2)
(2006): 200-205. [doi: 10.1257/000282806777212116]
- Devah Pager, Bruce Western, and Bart Bonikowski. ?Discrimination
in a Low Wage Labor Market: A Field Experiment.? American
Sociological Review 74(October): 777-799 [doi:
10.1177/000312240907400505]
- Paula England. "The
Failure of Human Capital Theory to Explain Occupational Sex
Segregation." The Journal
of Human Resources, Vol. 17, No. 3 (Summer, 1982), pp.
358-370 [jstor: 145585] and "Wage
Appreciation and Depreciation: A Test of Neoclassical Economic
Explanations of Occupational Sex Segregation." Social
Forces (1984) 62 (3): 726-749.
[doi: 10.1093/sf/62.3.726]
- Jos C. N. Raadschelders; "Size
and Organizational Differentiation in Historical Perspective";
Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory:
J-PART, Vol. 7, No. 3 (Jul., 1997), pp. 419-441 [jstor: 1181603]
- Devah Pager and Diana Karafin. "Bayesian
Bigot? Statistical Discrimination, Stereotypes, and Employer
Decision Making." The
Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science.
621 (January 2009): 70-93. [doi: 10.1177/0002716208324628]
- Kathryn M. Neckerman and Florencia Torche. "Inequality:
Causes and Consequences" Annu. Rev. Sociol.
2007. 33: 335-57. [doi: 10.1146/annurev.soc.33.040406.131755]
- Guillermina Jasso. "A
New Model of Wage Determination and Wage Inequality." Rationality
and Society 2009 21(1): 113-168. [doi:
10.1177/1043463108099350]
- Related
Readings
XIV. What makes some forms of inequality more
important than others to the organization of social structure and the
patterns of human action?
Some have argued that class dominates in particular societies or all
societies. Others have suggested that gender inequality is the most
fundamental inequality. Putting aside grand claims, most would agree
that some kinds of inequality have greater influence over the organization
of a society (or other social entity) and the history of that
organization. How we can systematically assess the relative
importance of different kinds of inequality and what decides their
differential importance are not clear.
- Analytical
Task
- Analytical task: To be added
- Select four kinds of inequality that are widespread within a
society or some other boundaried social context (such as an
organization or social category).
- Try to rank these examples of in equality in terms of their
relative importance.
- Note that different criteria for "importance" can result in
different rankings. One goal is to identify what
criteria for importance make sense for the chosen
examples.
- Note that the importance of an inequality may vary by time
period, by type of people, by location in another system of
inequality, and other differentiating conditions.
- Thus, a careful assessment will commonly result in a series
of rankings for the relative importance of the inequality
example, with the rankings distinguished by the criteria for
importance used and by the circumstances that mediate the
evaluations for any specific criterion.
- To be systematic, one will usually want to rewrite the
analysis of relative importance organized around the
conditioning criteria
- Having assessed the relative importance of the inequality
examples, try to explore what caused the rankings. In the
foregoing, we are focusing on description and measurement.
Here the concern is causality. Above we are trying to
establish why and when we might call one kind of inequality more
important than another, a conceptual and empirical exercise.
Here we are asking what it is about the content, configuration and
history of the inequalities that results in one having more
importance than the other.
- One path to answering this question might be to consider
known empirical examples where the relative importance of the
types of inequality being considered have a different ranking
importance.
- Another path to answering might be to imagine what it would
take to lower the importance of the higher ranked inequality
or raise the importance of the lower ranked one.
- Common Readings
- Recommended
Readings
- Related
Readings
XV. How does resistance by subordinate groups work?
&
People do not enjoy the lower status, fewer rewards, subjection to
authority, and other disadvantages attached to being at the lower end of
a system of inequality. This may result in anything between a
mild, occasional resentment and a continuous, burning hatred with
their fate. Fear, identification with the system, search for
praise from those above, or hope for personal advancement may induce
some to conform as much as possible with the expectations of the
advantaged. Still, wherever inequality exists, resistance
exists.
- Analytical
Task
- Analytical task: Resistance
- Select two examples of inequality. In each case, how do the
disadvantaged resist?
- While identifying resistance, consider <
- everyday, commonly repeated actions of the disadvantaged
- unusual, more extreme individual actions by some
disadvantaged
- collective or organized forms of resistance
- What conditions, rules, processes, and actions limit
resistance? To recognize these obstacles, consider why the
identified forms of resistance are not more common, more
extreme, or more effective?
- Common Readings
- Recommended
Readings
- Related
Readings
VIII. How can we understand the logic of structures of unequal
positions?
A system of inequality is a "system." From a functionalist
perspective, its persistence requires mechanisms to ensure conformity to
its rules and expectations, to recruit adequate personnel to sustain
operation, to preserve commitment of those in advantaged statuses and
limit rebellion from others, and so forth. From a structuralist
perspective, it will induce latent conflicts that must be contained, it
will require legitimating ideology, it must enforce unequal effort and
unequal rewards, and so forth. A system of inequality has
structure, it has processes that occur over time, it has mechanisms to
sustain itself. Are there ways we can conceive these elements that
allow us to talk with a common language about the structural logics of
diverse systems of inequality?
- Analytical
Task
- Analytical task.
- Select and list five or more
distinctive systems of inequality. From each of
the past weeks in this class, select one system of inequality
from the weekly papers . The possibilities from which to
choose includes any system of inequality that appears in any of
the papers for a given week.
- As usual, briefly describe each system of inequality.
Who are included, what is unequally distributed, who are
advantaged or disadvantaged, and the like. If you are
going to consider a subset of a larger system of inequality, be
clear about what you are doing and why.
-
- Common Readings
- Review readings of past weeks
-
- Recommended
Readings
- Related
Readings
*. What are general dimensions of inequality systems, by which we can
characterize, compare, and categorize them?
Generally, researchers and theorists treat different kinds of
inequalities as if they existed in distinct and unrelated
conceptual worlds, although they might empirically overlap in concrete
historical settings. Various empirical instances of racial
inequality are compared, as are different instances of income inequality
or organizational hierarchies, but divergent kinds of inequality each
get their own, independent analytic turf. The divisions between
"kinds" of inequality are not the result of any systematic logic, but
treated as self-evident, natural distinctions.
*. What might be general principles of systems of inequality? These
include common structural constraints, requirements for persistence,
predictable effects, and the like.
IX-2. {Optional – If Needed} How should we conceive interests in the
analysis of inequality? [part 2]
Continuing the analysis of interests.
- Analytical
Task
- Analytical Task 2 on Interests
- Taking into account the insights and concerns developed in the
Common Readings listed below, write a critical review of
Jackson's effort to use interests as a theoretical device and
analytical tool in the studies of class and gender inequality
listed above.
- How
to write a critical review
- Although scholars spend much time and effort writing critiques
of published work, and graduate students spend even more,
systematic treatments of the criteria for, and strategies
toward, good critiques are rare. Here are just a few points to
consider.
- A critique can never be better than its author's
understanding of the work being criticized. And a reader
cannot appreciate the intent of the critique beyond their grasp
of the critic's reading of the original work. This means
that to write a good critical review, we must first be sure we
understand what we are criticizing and, second, we must present
a clear summary of that understanding as part of our critique.
- Although there are important exceptions, most critical reviews
really are elaborations of the answer to a simple
question. After reading the piece, do I, the critic, find
the argument worthwhile or not? However elaborate or
simple, with whatever style of presentation, the review is
largely an effort to present a sustained defense of that
evaluation.
- A good review is always fair. We should never shy from
identifying a flaw or calling a mistake what it is. But we
should always try to use the language and tone that we hope
reviewers will use when they reveal the similar failings in our
work.
- We review manuscripts, articles, and books. We do
not review people. Brilliant scholars write dim
papers – they are not dim as a result. A wise reviewer
avoids referring to the author, and concentrates on the
strengths and weaknesses of the work being reviewed.
For example, saying that "the arguments in the last and
first sections contradict each other" is preferable to
saying "in the last section, the author contradicts what she
said in the first section". Attributing thoughts and
intentions to an author is worse. Sitting in judgment
of the author's intellect, effort, or morality is
worst.
- As reviewers, we commonly want to be clear about two
interpretations of what has been accomplished in the work
being reviewed: that of the author and that of the
reviewer. Sometimes these will be the same; often not.
A critic has no obligation to share the author's view
of the what has been done in the work. But the
scholarly critic does have an obligation to grasp and
accurately present the author's aims and orientation as they
are conveyed in the work.
- When an author sees a review, the author should not feel
(1) the reviewer has said or implied I said something that I
never said or implied or (2) the reviewer has said or
implied that I failed to consider something that is
explicitly part of my presentation.
- Good scholars do not mind critical reviews, even highly
critical ones, that are accurate and fair. Good
scholars despise reviews that are inaccurate or unfair, even
if they are positive.
- What a review covers depends on the review's purpose, the
audience, and the content and quality of the work being
reviewed. No possible recipe of ingredients will apply to
all or even most reviews. The closest we can come to this
is to list common elements of reviews, understanding that the
reviewer must judge what weight, if any, each merits in a
particular review. Some of these common elements to
consider in reviews include:
- Does the work have a central thesis, argument or claim
that is clear, relatively unambiguous, fully presented,
logically consistent, and not inherently flawed?
- Does the work adequately consider alternative arguments?
- Does the work provide evidence that effectively supports
the advocated claim over alternative claims?
- Is the evidence well chosen, properly gathered, and
effectively analyzed (or is the work methodologically
sound)?
- How compelling is the evidence?
- Does the work neglect or misconstrue some relevant
research or theory in ways that raise questions and
significantly diminish confidence in its claims?
- Are there serious logical flaws or gaps in the analysis?
- Overall, is the argument compelling?
- Overall, is the analysis a valuable contribution?
Or, does it have something to say that is worth
saying?
- Common Readings
- Recommended
Readings
- Related
Readings
*. What is the theoretical natural state: is it inequality or
equality that should be explained?
Sometimes a seemingly tangential question has the potential to gain us
unexpected insights. At least since Rousseau wrote the on the
origins of inequality we have been able to conceive that either equality
or inequality may be considered the problem to explain. While
modern sociology attributes little explanatory value to ideas about the
natural state of humankind, we may still hope to enhance our
understanding by juxtaposing efforts to identify the social mechanisms
responsible for inequality with those aimed at specifying the mechanisms
that induce equality.
VIII. How do people experience inequality and why do these
experiences matter – part 2?
This is a continuation of the previous week's topic
- Analytical
Task
- Analytical task. Rewrite analytical task of
last week.
- While rewriting, pay particular attention to the clear
identification of the systems of inequality. The examples
used may be a subset of a system, a particular context in a
system, or a location that is the intersection of two
systems. Try to clarify this as much as possible.
Try to think about what is unequal, and who are all the people
or all the positions that are related to those in the example
(and each other) by the inequality in the example.
- Recall that some examples of inequality amongst people are
more appropriately understood as the effects of a system of
inequality. If people have different quality housing as a
result of income inequality, we usually want to conceive of this
as an effect of income inequality, rather than analyzing housing
inequality as a system of inequality. The "system" of
inequality is where the causal dynamics between the advantaged
and disadvantaged are centered. There is no hard and fast
rule about the proper way to define a system of inequality,
because the optimal way of understanding an inequality will
depend on our analytical goals
- Common Readings
- Review readings of past weeks
-
- Recommended
Readings
- Review readings of past weeks
- ...
- Related
Readings
- Review readings of past weeks
- ...
To search this page, first click here [§] to reveal all the hidden text.
(Refresh page to rehide)